In the wake of two major bailouts, a decade apart, following
on a crash in 200-2001 and overshadowed by the twin phenomena of
de-industrialization and an enormous increase in wealth inequality that should
be compared not to the U.S. in the twenties but to Ancien regime France in the
1730s, the question arises: why do we have stock markets? And, more broadly, why have we allowed, or
even encouraged, the burgeoning of financial instruments in the post Bretton Woods period? The so
called shadow markets, or the other kind as well, that advertise themselves as
security for other financial instruments, but always not only fail in that
responsibility, but always crash themselves, bringing about chain reaction
crashes?
Peter L. Bernstein, who was an investor, journalist and
economist in one, observed that stock markets have increased in the post-war period
from around 50 in 1948 to around 125 in 1998. This speaks to something
attractive in the current period about the stock market. He examined the common
defense of the market in a great paper entitled Liquidity, Stock Markets and
Market Makers, published in 1987 – on the brink of Black Monday, 1987, when the
great Reagan stock boom crashed.
Bernstein considers the standard defense of the stock market
– that it allows liquidity and is an instrument for efficiency. Stocks, in this
story, reward innovation and that kind of efficiency that squeezes profits from
enterprises, allocating capital accordingly. On the other side, they punish
enterprises that stagnate and that fail to be “efficient”.
Bernstein does not leave the story there. In his paper, he
notes that the stock market system is embedded in and necessary to the corporation system: “One
of the great features of that legal creature we call the corporation is how readily
it facilitates transferring ownership in business. Perhaps the most impressive consequence
of that feature has been the development of organized stock markets.”
From that premise, Bernstein considers a tension – what a
Marxist would call a contradiction – between the two poles of efficiency and
liquidity:
“There is a tension between liquidity – a market in which we
can buy and sell promptly with minimal impact on the price of the stock – and efficiency
– a market in which prices move rapidly to reflect all new information as it
flows into the marketplace.”
Hark ye at the information talk. One of the fruits of the ‘cyborg
revolution” (to use Phllip Mirowski’s phrase) was the recasting of managerial
and speculative activity in terms of information. Bernstein’s essay quotes
amply from a lecture by Fischer Black entitled “Noise”, which is permeated with
the information paradigm. It refers to Claude Shannon’s distinction between
signal and noise. Primitively, these terms are just what they seem: if you broadcast
a message, there is an amount of static – noise – that adheres to it. If you write
down a message, there is a distortion in your handwriting that may make it hard
to read. “Noise” is the ‘friction of information. If you exchange information with
a person, the tone of your voice and expression on your face, your properties
in the socius, all of these come with that information. We realize this at some
Piagetian point in youth. Five year olds know how to say ‘yes’ to their parents
in a tone that signifies ‘no’ – this is the noise of raising a kid.
To return to the handy information paradigm in economics
(and observe my restraint: for those worried that I would get on the warpath
about Hayekian ideology, which rode piggyback on Shannon’s communication
science, rest assured – that isn’t my concern here) – Bernstein usefully takes
from Black the idea, paradoxical as it may seem, that ‘noise’ provides us with
the practical solution to our contradiction. Noise traders are essential to the
liquidity of the market. In fact, they are as essential as information traders.
Noise traders (“who trade on noise as though it were information”) are essential
for information traders to have to sell to or buy from: why? Because information
traders are, as it were, grouped at the efficiency end. Their “information
capital” restricts the incentive to trade “They are reluctant to trade with one
another, because, as Black puts it, “a trader with a special piece of information
will know that other traders have their own special pieces of information and
will therefore not automatically rush out to trade.” The P.T. Barnum principle
(there’s a sucker born every minute) has a systematic effect that often rewards
suckers and makes them useful, unbeknownst to themselves.
TO BE CONTINUED
No comments:
Post a Comment