In the wake of two major bailouts, a decade apart, following
on a crash in 200-2001 and overshadowed by the twin phenomena of
de-industrialization and an enormous increase in wealth inequality that should
be compared not to the U.S. in the twenties but to Ancien regime France in the
1730s, the question arises: why do we have stock markets? And, more broadly, why have we allowed, or
even encouraged, the burgeoning of financial instruments in the post Bretton Woods period? The so
called shadow markets, or the other kind as well, that advertise themselves as
security for other financial instruments, but always not only fail in that
responsibility, but always crash themselves, bringing about chain reaction
crashes?
Peter L. Bernstein, who was an investor, journalist and
economist in one, observed that stock markets have increased in the post-war
period from around 50 in 1948 to around 125 in 1998. This speaks to something
attractive in the current period about the stock market. He examined the common
defense of the market in a great paper entitled Liquidity, Stock Markets and
Market Makers, published in 1987 – on the brink of Black Monday, 1987, when the
great Reagan stock boom crashed.
Bernstein considers the standard defense of the stock market
– that it allows liquidity and is an instrument for efficiency. Stocks, in this
story, reward innovation and that kind of efficiency that squeezes profits from
enterprises, allocating capital accordingly. On the other side, they punish
enterprises that stagnate and that fail to be “efficient”.
Bernstein does not leave the story there. In his paper, he
notes that the stock market system is embedded in and necessary to the corporation system: “One
of the great features of that legal creature we call the corporation is how
readily it facilitates transferring ownership in business. Perhaps the most impressive
consequence of that feature has been the development of organized stock
markets.”
From that premise, Bernstein considers a tension – what a
Marxist would call a contradiction – between the two poles of efficiency and
liquidity:
“There is a tension between liquidity – a market in which we
can buy and sell promptly with minimal impact on the price of the stock – and
efficiency – a market in which prices move rapidly to reflect all new
information as it flows into the marketplace.”
Hark ye at the information talk. One of the fruits of the ‘cyborg
revolution” (to use Phllip Mirowski’s phrase) was the recasting of managerial
and speculative activity in terms of information. Bernstein’s essay quotes
amply from a lecture by Fischer Black entitled “Noise”, which is permeated with
the information paradigm. It refers to Claude Shannon’s distinction between
signal and noise. Primitively, these terms are just what they seem: if you
broadcast a message, there is an amount of static – noise – that adheres to it.
If you write down a message, there is a distortion in your handwriting that may
make it hard to read. “Noise” is the ‘friction of information. If you exchange
information with a person, the tone of your voice and expression on your face,
your properties in the socius, all of these come with that information. We
realize this at some Piagetian point in youth. Five year olds know how to say
‘yes’ to their parents in a tone that signifies ‘no’ – this is the noise of
raising a kid.
To return to the handy information paradigm in economics
(and observe my restraint: for those worried that I would get on the warpath
about Hayekian ideology, which rode piggyback on Shannon’s communication
science, rest assured – that isn’t my concern here) – Bernstein usefully takes
from Black the idea, paradoxical as it may seem, that ‘noise’ provides us with
the practical solution to our contradiction. Noise traders are essential to the
liquidity of the market. In fact, they are as essential as information traders.
Noise traders (“who trade on noise as though it were information”) are
essential for information traders to have to sell to or buy from: why? Because
information traders are, as it were, grouped at the efficiency end. Their
“information capital” restricts the incentive to trade “They are reluctant to
trade with one another, because, as Black puts it, “a trader with a special
piece of information will know that other traders have their own special pieces
of information and will therefore not automatically rush out to trade.” The
P.T. Barnum principle (there’s a sucker born every minute) has a systematic
effect that often rewards suckers and makes them useful, unbeknownst to
themselves.
Bernstein’s use of the dichotomy between information traders
and noise traders serves as a foundation for making some curious observations.
The one that concerns me is the “orderly” market. The
theoretical defense of the stock market is that it discourages “unnecessary”
volatility. Prices of stocks should point to some equilibrium valuation of the
enterprise that has issued the stock. But there is a problem:
“What happens if the fundamental value or equilibrium
level changes, however? In an orderly market, that change may take a long time
to appear, as the price meanders rather than leaps to its new equilibrium. In
that case, an orderly market is inefficient, in that its price information is
giving false signals to potential buyers and sellers. Here is where we would
want the noise traders to shut up and where market resiliency is a disadvantage
rather than an attraction. In other words, orderly is not always a desirable
property of a market.”
It is easy to read over economist’s prose, which seems
to be iced over just to make the laiety glide slip and tumble, never noticing the
enormities beneath his or her feet. Bernstein’s caveat here is basically that,
in solving the paradox posed by liquidity and efficiency, we slip out of the
true information defense of the market and admit that it is laced with false
information – or false “signals”. Because these are not immediately corrected –
because the market is constructed to slow volatility (especially going down –
an asymmetry that comes with wanting to sell stuff), over time synchronous and
chronic missignalling can and will happen. Whether the signaling is about the
value of Latin American mines (the cause of one of the first stock crashes, in
1830, when the Bank of England nearly went bankrupt) or the supposed risk
insured construction of mortgage backed securities, something is going to be
going wrong. This is not a contingent truth, but simply a result of the rules
of the market. It is as if you constructed a board game in which the very rules
incentivized cheating and covering up the cheating.
II.
Bridges sometimes collapse. Yet few people would argue
an anti-bridge position from that fact.
But what if bridges collapsed in unison? What if one
bridge collapsing in the U.S. caused half the bridges in the U.S. to collapse,
which in turn caused bridges to collapse in China, Japan, and Europe? Would
this change how we thought about bridges?
In 2008, according to D. McKennie, the collapse of the
NY stock market caused other markets to collapse as well, so that at the
end of 2008 35 trillion dollars worth of equity wealth was wiped out. This is
rather like my case of the bridge. The bridge is probably the most efficient
means to get people across rivers and abysses, but we would certainly want them
to be built with maximum attention to safety if they threatened to bring about
world-wide catastrophe if just one collapsed.
In actual fact, unlike bridges, there is one market more
than any other that has the capacity to bring all others down in its fall, and
that is the NYSE. However, this doesn’t really effect too much my parallel: we
would in fact seemingly want to make sure the NYSE is the best secured stock
market in the world given the structure of the international economy. And we
would want a clear idea of what it does best.
That idea is not helped by a theory that says: bridges
always operate efficiently, so that we don’t want to interfere with their
building. Or the idea that if bridges went down and killed millions of people,
but millions more than that theoretically flowed over them, everything is
cool.
My analogy is straining at the bit, or has broken the leash,
at this point. The point, this point, is that we don’t know if stock markets
are the most efficient ways to allocate capital if we don’t include in our
overview the fact that markets collapse.
When they collapse, there are always economists to say that
the collapse only costs unreal money money in excess of the value actually
destroyed. Which is another way of saying that the efficiency of the market is
paid for by each stock by some speculative prime – some effect of the famous price to earnings ratio. That is, for
most companies listed on the stock exchange, the value of the companies assets
and revenue are exponentially less than their capitalization. This is the root
of Piketty’s theory of the inequality structurally produced by capitalism.
In terms of efficiencies, the premium put on capitalization
seems oddly inefficient – do we really need to attract investment by creating
these chances for extraordinary wealth for the speculators? It is a question
that has been posed before, in the progressive era, when laws were considered
to put a cap on the amount an enterprise could be capitalized over its non-capitalized
value. This progressive proposal has fallen in the dust, along with so many
others. But as the financial markets both increase inequality and seem
inherently prone to massive government supports due to the crises endogenous to
their structures, we have to start dusting off these proposals again. We have
to start thinking about the abnormal size of the financial market in proportion
to its function, and the price we want to pay for this system of corporate
ownership. A question should haunt us: Does capitalism have to be this way?
No comments:
Post a Comment