Marx is not often pointed out to aspiring
writers for his imitable work in publicizing his masterpiece. However, the
correspondence of Marx and Engels, in 1867 and 1868, is filled with strategies
for making Capital known on a broad scale – from Engels suggestion that Marx
should take seriously the idea of a “portrait” in the Leipzig Illustrated Paper
to the campaign of reviews meant to pump the book.
Among the letters is one that is quoted
extensively by Schlomo Avineri in his essay trying to prove that the connection
between Marx and Darwin came about as
the result of a hoax. Avineri cherrypicks a bit in this essay: Marx, who was no
biologist, was alternatively impressed by Darwin and scornful of the way he
took Malthus’ method and applied it to nature (I should say, from comments of
Darwin’s this is what Marx took Darwin to be doing, although of course the
issue is more complex than that). Still, it gave Avineri the chance to quote a
quite amazing letter in which Marx pens a review of Das Capital that criticizes
its “subjective” anti-capitalist tendencies while praising its general tenor.
Its quite an amusing text:
“As regards the little Swabian paper, it
would be an amusing coup if we could hoodwink Vogt’s friend, the Swabian Mayer.
It would be easy to contrive the thing as follows. D'abord to begin by saying that
whatever one may think of the draft of the book, it is a credit to the ‘German spirit’,
for which reason, too, it was written by a Prussian in exile and not in
Prussia; Prussia having long ceased to be a country where any scholarly
initiative, especially in the political or historical or social field, is
possible or is actually to be found, it now being the representative of the
Russian and not of the German spirit. In respect of the book itself, a
distinction has to be drawn between two things, between positive developments
(’solid’ would be the second epithet) given by the author, and the tendentious
conclusions he arrives at. The former are a direct addition to the sum of human
knowledge, since actual economic relations are treated in an entirely new way
by a materialistic (‘Mayer’ has a liking for this catchword, on account of
Vogt) method. Example: 1. the development of money, 2. the way
in which co-operation, division of labour, the machine system and the
corresponding social combinations and relations develop ‘spontaneously’.
Now as regards the tendency of the author, another
distinction has to be drawn. When he demonstrates that present society,
economically considered, is pregnant with a new, higher form, he is only
showing in the social context the same gradual process of evolution that Darwin
has demonstrated in natural history. The liberal doctrine of ‘progress’ (c'est Mayer tout pur) embraces this idea, and it
is to his credit that he himself shows there is hidden progress even where
modern economic relations are accompanied by frightening direct consequences.
At the same time, owing to this critical approach of his, the author has,
perhaps malgré lui , sounded
the death-knell to all socialism by the book, i.e. to utopianism, for evermore.
The author’s tendency to be subjective, on the other hand — which he
was perhaps bound and obligated to assume in view of his party position and his
past — i.e. the manner in which he represents to himself or to others the
ultimate outcome of the present movement, of the present social process, bears
absolutely no relation to its real development. If space permitted this to be
more closely examined, it could perhaps be shown that its ‘objective’
development refutes his own ‘subjective’ fancies.
Whereas Mr Lassalle hurled abuse at the
capitalists and flattered the backwoods Prussian squirearchy, Mr Marx, on the
contrary, shows the historical necessity of capitalist production and
severely criticises the landed aristocrat who does nought but consume. Just how
little he shares the ideas of his renegade disciple Lassalle on Bismarck’s
vocation for ushering in an economic millennium he has not merely shown in his
previous protests against ‘royal Prussian
Socialism’ but he openly repeats it on pp. 762, 763, where he says that
the system prevailing in France and Prussia at present will subject the
continent of Europe to the regime of the Russian knout, if it is not checked in
good time.
That is my view on how to hoodwink the
Swabian Mayer (who did after all print my preface), and small though his
beastly rag is, it is, nevertheless, the popular oracle of all the Federalists
in Germany and is also read abroad.”
This purely gleeful side of Marx is what
makes him a manyhandled author – note the scorn connected with the world “materialist”,
and the surprisingly turn at the end of the pseudo-review in which Capital is taken as the death knell of
socialism. In fact, this view of the book has, outside of Marx’s “hoax”,
endured, with the “rational expectations” Marxists of the 80s – I’m looking at
you, Jon Elster – making it the centerpiece of their radicaly purified Marxism.
So, here’s Marx’s advice to young writers:
get your friends to write reviews of your book in which they praise it for its
objective merits, but qualify the praise by saying that the author’s viewpoint
is, unfortunately, completely wrong.
Marx was ahead of his time: what he was
doing was inventing the flame war as a way to sell his book.
No comments:
Post a Comment