In 1790, 75 percent of the working population of Austria was
involved with agriculture (David Good); this was true of 73 percent of the population of the U.S. at
the time, and approximately the same percentage
in Prussia as well (Cambridge Economic History). In Europe as a whole, at the
time of the French Revolution, when we look not only at the population that
directly labored in the fields, but include those who depended directly on
them, we get even more elevated figures: 90 percent, for instance, for France. The exceptions are
Britain and Holland, with the percentage being as low it is estimated as 40 percent in Britain. These were the first economies to enduringly get past what the
growth economists call “Malthusian limits” – that is, an agricultural sector that
shrinks in population size while growing in productivity such that it can
support a much larger non-agricultural population. The post-Malthusian world is
the world of the artificial paradise, in which I, and everybody I know, has
lived all our lives – except when escaping in little pockets of fantasy, sleep,
digestion, sex, the third life, and phobias.
It is hard to measure these pockets. But we can confidently say that in
other places, the Malthusian world lingered on – in Galicia, or in Russia, or in
China and India. And the breaking of the Malthusian limits was in many ways a
huge trauma, involving starvation, the total breakdown of cultural constants,
emigration, loneliness, and changes in the internal signaling structure of our
bodies and emotions that we are still grappling with on a world wide scale.
In the post-Malthusian world, the productive and the
unproductive took on different characteristics. It was no longer of a small
merchant class, nobility, and an overwhelming peasantry. It was no longer Robin
Hood’s world. Marx’s world was that of the nation on the forefront of
industrialization – England – but even in Marx’s time, the elements that would
subordinate the sphere of production to the sphere of circulation were in
evidence.
As Murray Smith (1993) has pointed out, Marx’s comments
about productive and unproductive labor in the second book of Capital don’t
cohere, completely, with his comments in the Grundrisse. Smith usefully defines
four forms of unproductive labor: Smith’s form, in which labor is paid for out
of personal revenue, such as household labor; labor of the self-employed
commodity producer; labor of the circulation worker; and what he calls
“social-maintenance” labor.
Smith’s definitions are all derived from the social position
of the laborer with regard to capital. Productive labor, then, is not about
producing a material thing, but about producing surplus value. The salesman and
the teacher can both be exploited, in this reading, when we look at their labor
from the point of view of the total social product, but they are not exploited
as productive labor is exploited. What is important is not to see these forms
as fixed elements in the social picture, but rather as frontiers always
susceptible to be changed in their location in the social whole. If we put the
sphere of circulation at one end, as a constant parameter of non-productive
labor, we cannot really make the same claim about other non-productive workers.
Edward
Wolff puts it like this: “Unproductive activity
affects the disposition of commodities
but creates neither use value nor exchange value.
Productive labor creates surplus value; unproductive labor absorbs surplus
value.” (1987)
It is
in the cruel intersection of these two sentences that I locate that lonely
beast, the modern writer.
1 comment:
".. the third life..." What is this, and more importantly where can I buy it?
Post a Comment